by Benjamin Marks, Economics.org.au editor-in-chief

It was great to see Neville Kennard’s comment on the lack of radicalism and success of think tanks featured in the latest IPA Review, complete with a distinguished response from Senator Cory Bernardi. Without wanting to appear too demanding or ungrateful, I found Bernardi’s response insincere and unconvincing.

Senator Bernardi offers the following vague criticism of Kennard’s anarchocapitalism: “[W]hile most of us want the maximum possible level of freedom, there must always be constraints on unfettered freedom as part of living in a civil society.” Does Bernardi honestly intend with that comment to convince Kennard he is wrong? What is the motive of such a trite I-will-not-engage-but-will-make-my-objection-known comment? Imagine if I were to respond to Bernardi’s sentence with my own: “In a civil society there must always be freedom to do whatever you want with what is justly yours, provided you don’t violate the right of others to do the same.” It is a debate where you don’t go past introducing yourself: a duel without a showdown, a nodding and shaking of heads, a whistling and muttering, a yak and a nay. Kennard’s attempt to debate remains unrequited and unconsummated. He has been left at the altar of government sacrifice. He has been stood up, left hanging and given the tax bill. How about defining terms like “unfettered”, “freedom”, “government”, “liberty” and “self-ownership”?

Bernardi’s comment implies that Kennard’s philosophy has failed to address whether people have the right to murder and to defend themselves from murder (what else could Bernardi’s use of “unfettered freedom” be meant to mean?). This shows lack of sincerity in dealing with Kennard’s criticism. At the end of the unabridged version of his essay (available here), Kennard provides recommended reading, which accessibly explain anarchocapitalism. Furthermore, I assume Bernardi was informed about Kennard’s association with Economics.org.au, yet despite our ridiculously prominent statements of anarchocapitalist reasoning on the middle and right columns of every page, Bernardi fails to engage with it at all.

As for the fact that think tanks have had success in getting attention for free-market ideas and even acceptance for them. I concede the point, as I make clear here. But everyone will admit that the success the IPA has had is insufficient to make their strategies and the strength of their reasoning immune from debate and beyond reproach. And debate over strategy and free-market principles is precisely what Kennard’s article and Economics.org.au itself is trying to bring about. It is unfortunate, therefore, that the IPA would respond to Kennard’s anarchocapitalism with one trite statement of disagreement rather than criticism, and respond to his criticism of their success with a single case study.

Given the fact that Kennard has for over 30 years contributed a bit more than most to free-market think tanks in Australia, perhaps an attempt to engage with his anarchocapitalism and his criticism of the lack of principles, lack of radicalism (even within classical liberalism) and lack of non-utilitarian reasoning in espousing free-markets is in order. You have successfully communicated that you disagree with Kennard’s criticism. We would now like you to explain why you disagree.

Lastly, please read my clear list of criticisms here, for a fuller explanation of where Economics.org.au disagrees with the IPA.