by Benjamin Marks, Economics.org.au editor-in-chief

There are some uncritically accepted positions that most MPS 2010 Sydney Meeting attendees and speakers, and, while we’re at it, CIS and IPA types, believe. I think the following sequences crystallise a few of the areas where their thinking differs with mine, making it easy to see my criticism, without me needing to quote from their papers, which would violate Chatham House Rules. Some of the sequences list ideas that were neglected and some juxtapose simultaneously held conflicting ideas.1

Sequence I: Goalpost Moving; Logical Extremism=Error
  1. That it is possible to differentiate between the morality of different levels of taxes, when the different levels of taxation are brought about by the same process (parliamentary democracy or whatever), with the same utilitarian arguments in justification.
  2. That this moral argument magically turns into a practicality argument at the whim of its exponent.
  3. That to be consistent in your morality is to be an anarchist.
  4. That anarchocapitalists take things to the logical extremes.
  5. That taking things to their logical extremes is an example of fallacious reasoning.
  6. That taking things to their logical extremes is extreme in a bad way.
  7. That taking things to their logical extremes is to be excluded from public debate.
  8. That it is known in advance when you will be excluded from public debate, even if you are a “respectable” public figure or institution.
  9. That since it is already known that speaking out about certain things won’t make a difference, one must not speak out about them.
  10. That academics and activists know what will and what won’t make a difference, even if they don’t write or reference any investigations into strategy.
  11. That radicalism is important, and we must not compromise.
Sequence II: Transaction Cost Flaws Ignored
  1. That the concept of externalities has now been replaced by the concept of transaction costs.
  2. That Austrian school criticism of public goods and transaction costs are unknown. (For example, Walter Block on transaction costs here and here, on public goods here, and Hoppe on public goods here.)
  3. That there are many free market solutions to environmental problems, but that Rothbard’s brilliant essay is unknown or not worth trumpeting at every chance.
Sequence III: MPS as Rabelais’ Crazy Council
  1. That consequentialist and utilitarian arguments are what libertarianism/classical liberalism is all about.
  2. That behavioural and happiness economics are a threat to free markets.
  3. That Austrian school criticism of consequentialism and utilitarianism (which includes transaction cost arguments), showing how it fails to treat utility as subjective and how this failure opens the door for behavioural and happiness economics, is unknown.
  4. That the MPS meeting was like Rabelais’ Crazy Council where heretics go to better deal with new styles of heretics (uses of utilitarianism need to conform to their use of utilitarianism, which makes all the same mistakes, but differently):

The next day, on our starboard side, we met up with nine old tub boats full of monks — Dominicans, Jesuits, Capuchins, Hermits, Augustinians, Bernardines, Celestines, Theatines, Egnatins, Amadeans, Franciscans, Carmelites, Minims, and monks named for all the other holy saints — who were on their way to the Crazy Council, where they were going to polish up the articles of faith so they could deal with new styles of heretics. [François Rabelais, Gargantua and Pantagruel, trans. Burton Raffel (New York: Norton, 1991), bk. 4, ch. 18, p. 428]

Sequence IV: On John Howard
  1. That John Howard implemented as much free-market reform as he could, after calculating how much he would have to compromise to keep the other party out, as long as he didn’t have to compromise so much that the other party became preferable.
  2. That John Howard was a pragmatist with no ideological framework, and, a compromiser.
  3. That John Howard did much to decrease the size of government.
  4. That a tendentious list of examples will always fool an audience. (For a more balanced and fact-based rather than rhetoric-based approach, see Andrew Norton here and here and Robert Carling here. Also, readers may be interested in my exclusive and scandalous interview with Howard on his autobiography here.)
  5. That John Howard was influenced by Bert Kelly.
Sequence V: Radicalism is Good, YET Gov Funding is OK
  1. That it is fashionable to defend government funding, whilst: criticising government management; ignoring that the same arguments used to criticise government management apply equally to government funding; and praising the fact that this toned down version is radical and that radicalism is the way to go.
  2. That it is never made clear whether the author is not advocating the full anarchocapitalist position because he does not actually believe it is justifiable, or, whether it is because he is compromising for strategic reasons, believing that if he tones down his position he is more likely to get a hearing.
  3. Since one is not meant to quote from MPS papers, I quote from the most recent CIS publication, written by Professor Wolfgang Kasper2: “I accept for the present discussion that most Australians do not want their average fellow citizens to be massively out of pocket for the cost of births, surgery and hospital stays … If we take this public choice as a given in our affluent and egalitarian society, it follows that every NSW citizen should have access to necessary hospital services irrespective of his or her financial condition” (pp. 37-38, emphasis mine). Why this “accepting for the present discussion” and “taking as given”? Is it for strategic reasons, as suggesting an end to government funding of healthcare would be too radical? Well, since strategy is an art rather than a science, that would be fair enough, although I would appreciate if someone could find for me an essay on strategy by the author or publisher, where they explain why being consistently radical is bad strategy. In any case, this would appear not to be the reason, as at the end of the essay, the same author says, “Radical reform is never easy and naturally meets with scepticism. It is the role of the policy analyst to develop alternative ideas, however costly and uncomfortable, and expose them to public and expert scrutiny — so that political leaders can implement them, as and when the old system fails so badly that even politicians discover that radical surgery is the only politically convenient solution” (p. 53, emphasis mine). How can this passage be reconciled with the one on pp. 37-38?
Footnotes
  1. The format is inspired by Flaubert’s Dictionary of Accepted Ideas and Mencken and Nathan’s American Credo.
  2. Wolfgang Kasper, “Radical Surgery: The Only Cure for Public Hospitals,” in No Quick Fix: Three Essays on the Future of the Australian Hospital System (St Leonards, Australia: The Centre for Independent Studies, 2010). It is amusing to compare the “12-Point Plan to Fix Hospitals” in No Quick Fix with Hoppe’s infinitely more biting “Four-Step Health-Care Solution.”